Rachael Sotos is a political theorist and adjunct professor with a background in philosophy, classics and environmental studies.
Climate Shock: The Economic Consequences of a Hotter Planet, is both a tidy summation of the state of the art in climate economics and a powerful call for action. For all the uncertainties and challenges, “the overall policy framework needed for addressing climate change is clear and has been for decades,” state co-authors Gernot Wagner and Martin L. Weitzman (p. 23). “Carbon dioxide is the problem. Pricing it properly is the solution.”(38)
Wagner, a senior economist at the Environmental Defense Fund, and Weitzman, a celebrated economist at Harvard, are an intriguing blend of young and elder, and realist and idealist. They exhort economists and climate advocates to get past the “epic debates” between taxes and cap-and-trade and, while consensus builds toward carbon pricing, to engage in the work required for “second -, third-, and fourth-best solutions”(26): electricity grid reform, stronger CAFE standards, and strategic application of subsidies and U.S. EPA regulations. “At the very least,” they say, “these regulations could provide a real bargaining chip when it comes to U.S. Congress considering comprehensive climate policy and a direct price on carbon down the line.”(19).
Flying their Pigovian colors from Preface to Epilogue, the authors are emphatic and unambiguous; “Putting a proper price on carbon isn’t a question of if, it’s a question of when.”(xi) Our best hope is “a high enough price on carbon to reflect its true cost to society.”(152)
Unfortunately, the bracing clarity of Climate Shock appears to have been lost on some reviewers. Earlier this month, NY Times columnist Joe Nocera misconstrued Wagner and Weitzman’s extensive discussion of geo-engineering as surrender to the political obstacles to carbon pricing. On Nocera’s reading, insofar as “a carbon tax on the worst emitters has gotten nowhere,” it’s time for Plan B: “chemo for the planet.” Au contraire, Wagner and Weitzman do not delve into geo-engineering scenarios like sulfates dispersal in lieu of ambitious policies to reduce emissions. Rather, they insist, “the specter of geo-engineering should be a clarion call for action. Decisive, and soon.”(29)
If Nocera reconfigured Wagner and Weitzman to suit his own techno-utopian ends, Yale Nobel economist Robert J. Shiller, also in the Times, willfully invested Climate Shock with libertarian designs. Directly contravening the thoughtful and informative discussion of social change presented in Climate Shock (and previously thematized in Wagner’s 2011 But Will the Planet Notice?), Shiller proposed idealistically-motivated incrementalism as a way around Kyoto’s failure “to impose strict taxes on carbon emissions.”
According to Shiller, Wagner and Weitzman “say that we should be asking people to save our climate by taking many small, individual actions.” Climate Shock actually says the opposite: “the numbers don’t add up. They’ll only begin to add up when environmentalists use their collective political powers to move the policy needle in the right direction, toward a price on carbon.”(40) (See also CTC director Charles Komanoff’s recent takedown of Shiller’s piece in regard to both facts and theory.)
Shiller’s misreading is doubly unfortunate because, as Wagner and Weitzman point out, the imperative to seriously engage policy must be directed toward average citizens, “those in the middle of the political spectrum,” as well as those already conversant with climate economics.(136) Certainly we should all do what we can to encourage virtuous cycles of ethical engagement and political participation – “Recycling well leads to better environmental policies, which allow for a more environmentally enlightened citizenry; a more enlightened citizenry, in turn, leads to more people recycling well.”(132)
Indeed. But, as Wagner and Weitzman are right to remind: in a greenwashed world seemingly structured to distract and misinform the average person, the most virtuous deeds can dead end. In the practical economics of everyday life, single actions sometimes crowd out other forms of engagement: “when people substitute single, individual actions – like recycling – for larger policy actions – like voting.”(133) Pigovians from start to finish, Wagner and Weitzman are emphatic: “if you have to make a choice between recycling and voting for a price on carbon, choose voting.”(137)
Yet another review, this one by Yale economist William D. Nordhaus in the current New York Review of Books, is notable on several grounds, not least of which is Nordhaus’s outsized reputation as a pioneering climate economist and modeler. Respectful in tone, Nordhaus engages of Climate Shock’s discussions of geo-engineering, the economics of uncertainty and the pitfalls of negotiating climate treaties. Strangely, however, Nordhaus takes up Weitzman’s path-breaking analyses of catastrophic risk without acknowledging any critiques of his own perennially optimistic approach.
To be sure, the point of Climate Shock is not to decry the modeling efforts of Nordhaus and other climate economists. “Getting things right is incredibly difficult . . . If anything we should be supercharging [carbon pricing models]: IBM-ifying their operation.”(60) It is one thing to calculate “the known knowns”; here, as Wagner and Weitzman explain, Nordhaus’s own modeling is “perennially playing catch up with the latest science.”(59) But the real difficulty is with the “tipping points and other nasty surprises” hidden behind every corner, the “unknown unknowns” that “may yet dominate,” (56) and overwhelm Nordhaus’s casualness.
Evident in the title of the review, “A New Solution: the Climate Club,” is Nordhaus’s failure to directly engage the apparent chasm between his own approach and Wagner and Weitzman’s implicit view of the relationship between politics and economics. Wagner and Weitzman are intent to situate climate economics within traditional institutional frameworks (finance, insurance, legality), while Nordhaus (and Shiller) prefer to subordinate politics to economics.
Of course, as Nordhaus rightly points out, neither he nor the authors of Climate Shock ally themselves with the call to “overcome capitalism” (e.g., Naomi Klein). Yet a specter is lurking behind Nordhaus’s call for business-friendly “climate clubs” modeled on organizations such as the EU, WTO and/or “military alliances.” Climate clubs a la Nordhaus seek to address the “free-rider” problem regionally, through tariffs on non-participants, but without supervision by external political spectators or truly international institutions.
It is telling that Nordhaus neglects to mention Climate Shock’s more universalistic aspirations, e.g., the “latest theoretical insights” offered by Weitzman himself regarding the potential significance of carbon taxing as the way to untangle international climate negotiations. (25) (See CTC senior policy analyst James Handley’s recent account of Weitzman’s research.) Here is Climate Shock’s summation of the potential of “homogenous carbon pricing” to overcome the free-rider problem:
The latest theoretical insights point to how taxes may allow for easier international coordination. In theory at least, negotiating a uniform tax rate, the proceeds from which are retained by each country, engenders an ever-so-subtle way of countervailing the force of the free-rider problem altogether. If we all agreed on a uniform tax rate per unit of carbon dioxide, then raising the tax would hurt me directly by raising my cost of using carbon-emitting energy but would help me because it makes everyone else cut down on their carbon dioxide emissions as well. By contrast, negotiating caps alone creates the clear incentive for wanting laxer caps. Negotiating a uniform, global tax can achieve something close to the global optimal outcome. (26)
It remains to be seen if a convergence can be found between Nordhaus’s “climate clubs” and Wagner and Weitzman’s more universal, politically-attuned, designs. One key aspect that must be reconciled, of course, is the price itself. If $40 per ton (the present social cost of carbon dioxide, according to the U.S. government) is “the outside” of what is imaginable for Nordhaus, but the apparent bare minimum for Wagner and Weitzman, this negotiation had better get started soon.
James Handley says
Hi Rachael,
On your recommendation, I’ve ordered “Climate Shock.” I appreciate Weitzman’s contributions challenging cost-benefit analysis that minimizes high risk climate scenarios, and his recent lucid articulation of the advantages of negotiating a global carbon price. Thanks for sketching how badly Nocera, Shiller and Nordhaus’s reviews seem to miss Wagner & Weitzman’s big points. I look forward to reading the straight story.
marsha anderson says
excellent review
James Handley says
Climate Shock was also favorably reviewed in “Strategy and Business.” Here’s an excerpt:
Harriet R Shugarman says
Thanks Rachel, well done…If we can all get behind just two initiatives: 1. a carbon tax, and 2. voting only for candidates that have a clearly articulated and thought out action plan to address climate change, we will be well on our way to a less frightening and devastating future.
I look forward to reading the Climate Shock.
Jim Stodder says
The last paragraph, counterposing the Weitzman-Wagner uniform carbon tax with the Nordhaus Climate Club proposal, is written without understanding the latter. Nordhaus’s theoretical and empirical model strongly supports what Weitzman-Wagner are saying — and Nordhaus also wants a global carbon price/tax. The only difference in his “club” approach is that it shows a way of achieving such a tax among independent states — without having to wait for a global government that might be capable of imposing it.