Cap-and-Trade Becomes a Bludgeon in Republican Primary Brawl (NYT-ClimateWire)
Carbon offsets near record low, worst performing commodity
Carbon Offsets Near Record Low, Worst Performing Commodity (Reuters)
Natural Gas: Cleaner, Not Cooler
Natural Gas Boom Could Spur Energy Demand, Obliterating Climate Benefits (Economist)
Why Setting The Social Cost of Carbon Is Like Sound Parenting
The U.S. may not yet have an actual carbon price, i.e., a carbon tax, but last year, a federal Interagency Working Group set a virtual “social cost of carbon” to be used in governmental cost-benefit analyses policies that affect energy and climate. This official estimate of the social cost of carbon — it was later formalized in a Department of Energy rule — is $21/ton of CO2, a figure that equates to around 20 cents per gallon of gasoline and 9/10 of a cent per kilowatt-hour sold.
You can view the social cost of carbon, or SCC, as an estimate of the “true” climate cost of fossil fuels — the cost of doing nothing about global warming. In economic theory it’s the “optimal” Pigovian carbon price or tax – the levy that would tell decision-makers across the economy how much effort to make to reduce CO2 emissions to minimize economic harm from global warming. If the SCC is set too low, economic actors won’t do enough to avert disaster; if it’s too high, we’ll overreact and suppress otherwise economical uses of fossil fuels.
Determining the appropriate or optimal SCC is a bit like deciding how much to spend on fire insurance — except that in this instance we know that if we do nothing, there’s a “fire” coming; we just don’t have a good handle on how bad it will be or when it will burn out of control. Now, a new, peer-reviewed report, “Revising the Social Cost of Carbon,” by economists Frank Ackerman and Elizabeth Stanton of the E3 Network, argues persuasively that DOE’s rule has set the social cost of carbon far too low.
Ackerman and Stanton identify assumptions about three crucial parameters that led the Working Group to substantially under-estimate the SCC:
1) Climate Sensitivity. This term carries a specific meaning in climate discourse: how much warmer Earth’s climate will get, on average, if CO2 concentrations in the atmosphere double from the historic 270 ppm to 540 ppm. Not long ago, the working consensus among climate scientists was that climate sensitivity (CS) was about 3 degrees Celsius (5 degrees Fahrenheit). But CS has always been expressed in ranges. For example, while the 2007 IPCC Fourth Assessment Report used the 3 degree C figure for CS, it also estimated that there is at least a 1-in-20 chance that doubling the CO2 concentration will cause 7 degrees C of warming, meaning that the Earth’s atmosphere may be more than twice as sensitive to CO2 as is generally assumed.
To get a feel for the magnitude of that much warming, consider that the difference between our climate today and that of the last ice age, when North America was covered by glaciers, is only about 8 degrees C. To the extent that scientists have overlooked important feedback mechanisms that will make the Earth get hotter as CO2 levels rise, CS will need to be revised upward.
2) Damage Severity. How much harm will any given amount of warming cause and how soon? Ackerman and Stanton critique the Working Group estimates which relied heavily on modeling by noted Yale economist William Nordhaus. They found that his damage function is set so low that it predicts half of world economic activity would continue even when Earth’s temperature had risen 19 degrees C! In contrast, Harvard economist Martin Weitzman estimates that “just” 6 degrees C of warming would wipe out half of world economic activity. For support, Weitzman cites estimates published in the proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences that a global-average 12 degrees C rise would leave large parts of the world experiencing heat episodes at least once a year that no humans could survive. Needless to say, this suggests that Nordhaus is far too sanguine on damage severity, and that the Working Group’s estimate of the social cost of carbon is far too low.
3) Discount Rate. Discounting is the economist’s tool for quantifying the importance of future consequences in present-day decisions. The choice of a high discount rate makes the future seem farther off and represents an implicit assumption that future well-being is less important. A low discount rate weighs the future more heavily. (To give high-discount rate economists their due, they argue that innovation will allow future society to cope and, indeed, prosper better than supposedly “static” models give credit for.)
If we assume that the future will be prosperous and that humans can adapt to a drastically-altered world, maybe it’s not so bad to lose half of whatever we now value in life to the ravages of global warming. But if the future looks like a long stretch of hard times, or if preserving some semblance of “traditional” nature and society is accorded some intrinsic value, then losing half might really be painful, especially if it means we lose half of our food production.
The Working Group used a relatively high discount rate of 3% in arriving at its SCC of $21/ton. Ackerman and Stanton point to the Stern Review of the Economics of Climate Change which used 1.5%. At bottom, the discount rate is a value judgment, akin to the question of how much to save for your 2-year-old’s education. But like the decision to start saving early, the discount rate affects results later very strongly.
Revised Estimates: Ackerman and Stanton argue that unrealistically low damage assumptions combined with over-discounting cause the official SCC of $21 to be many times too low. Using a range of assumptions from models and assessments that they consider more realistic, they calculate SCC values ranging from $56 to $893. While this range is obviously extremely broad and heavily dependent on assumptions, Ackerman and Stanton also point out that when the social cost of carbon — essentially the present value of the future damage if we do nothing about climate — passes a certain point, standard cost-benefit analysis stops making sense. In that situation, any action we can take to reduce carbon emissions is virtually guaranteed to cost less than the discounted present value of the damage.
Translated into pricing policy, this means that if a carbon tax is meant to internalize the social cost of carbon, it needs to aim high. While there are downsides to setting the carbon tax very high initially, it needs to rise (and be expected to rise) briskly enough to induce as much reduction in CO2 emissions as fast as our economy can deliver.
In short, the message of “Revising the Social Cost of Carbon” sounds like time-honored parental advice: Start modestly, don’t delay, and aim high. Ironically, it’s Generation Hot — to use journalist Mark Hertsgaard’s evocative phrase — who will need to deliver that message to their elders, rather than the reverse.
Photo: Flickr — Betty Bye
Debt and (carbon) taxes: Obama’s last chance for climate redemption
Debt and Carbon Taxes: Obama’s Chance for Climate Redemption (Joe Romm, Grist)
The Social Cost of Carbon — How Much Insurance To Buy?
The U.S. Department of Energy’s official estimate of the “Social Cost of Carbon” (SCC) is $21/ton of CO2, which amounts t0 $0.21/gallon of gasoline. That’s the weighting factor (set by DOE rule) used to decide how much importance to give to the future damage from global warming in a panoply of decisions both inside and outside government. The SCC can be viewed as an estimate of the “true” cost of fossil fuels — the cost of doing nothing about global warming. In economic theory it’s the “optimal” Pigouvian carbon price or tax — it would tell us how much effort to make to reduce our CO2 emissions to minimize economic harm from global warming. But if the SCC estimate is too small, we won’t do enough to avert disaster; if it’s too large we’ll over-react. Setting the SCC is a bit like deciding how much to spend on fire insurance– except that in this instance, we know that if we do nothing, there’s a “fire” coming, we just don’t have a good handle on how bad it will be or when it will get really bad. According to “Revising the Social Cost of Carbon,” by economists Frank Ackerman and Elizabeth Stanton (E3 Network), the government’s SCC estimate is far too low because of three crucial assumptions:
1) Climate Sensitivity. How warm will Earth’s climate get if we double CO2 levels from the historic 270 ppm to 540 ppm? The working consensus among climate scientists is that CS is about 3 degrees Celsius (5 degrees Fahrenheit). But four years ago, the IPCC concluded that there’s at least a 5% chance that CS is 7 degrees C. For a sense of that magnitude, the difference between our climate and that of the last ice age (when North America was covered by glaciers) was about 8 degrees C. Recent data and weather events suggest that CS will need to be revised upward– scientists have almost certainly overlooked some important feedback mechanisms that will make the Earth get hotter as CO2 levels rise.
2) Severity of Damage from global warming. How much harm will a given amount of warming cause and how soon? Ackerman and Stanton critique the DOE estimates which are based in part on work by economist William Nordhaus which assumes that half of world economic activity would continue even when Earth’s temperature had risen 19 degrees C. In contrast, economist Martin Weitzman estimates that 6 degrees C would wipe out half of world economic activity. Credible estimates suggest that a 12 degrees C rise would result in large parts of the world experiencing temperatures at least once a year too high for humans to survive, suggesting that Nordhaus’ (and DOE’s) estimate is far too low.
3) Discount Rate. Discounting reduces the importance of the future by making it seem farther off. A high discount rate represents an assumption that future well-being is less important than a low discount rate which weighs the future more heavily in our present-day decisions. If we assume that the future will be prosperous, maybe it’s not so bad to lose half of whatever we value in life to the ravages of global warming. But if the future looks like a long stretch of hard times, losing half might really be painful, especially if we lose half of our food production. DOE uses a discount rate of 3%; Ackerman and Stanton point to the Stern review which used 1.5%. In some ways, the discount rate is a value judgment, somewhat like the question of how much to save for your child’s education when she’s only 2 years old. But like the decision to start saving early, the discount rate affects results later very strongly, especially when the potential for larger future damages is also factored in.
Ackerman and Stanton argue that low damage assumptions and over-discounting mean that the official $21 figure is far too low. Using a range of more realistic assumptions, they calculate SCC values ranging from $56 to $893. But they point out that when the SCC — essentially the present value of the future damage if we do nothing about climate — becomes large enough, standard cost-benefit analysis stops making sense. In that situation, any effective action we can take will cost less than the discounted present value of the damage. Translated into pricing policy, that means that if a carbon tax is meant to internalize the social cost of carbon, it needs to aim high. There may be little advantage in setting the carbon tax very high initially, but it needs to rise and be expected to rise briskly enough to induce as much reduction in CO2 emissions as fast as our economy can deliver.
In short, the message of “Revising the Social Cost of Carbon” sounds like parental advice: Start modestly, don’t delay, and aim high. Ironically, it’s Generation Hot who will need to deliver that message to its elders.
British PM praises Gillard's carbon tax
Conservative British PM Praises Gillard’s Carbon Tax As “Bold and Ambitious” (Big Pond News)
Could A Carbon Tax Help Solve Our Budget Woes? (Ben Schreiber – Grist)
DeChristopher sentenced to prison, 26 protesters arrested
Judge Says DeChristopher’s Defiant Statements Called For Harsh Sentence (Utah News)
The carbon tax is working nicely
British Columbia’s Carbon Tax is Working Nicely (Sydney Morning Herald)
- « Previous Page
- 1
- …
- 49
- 50
- 51
- 52
- 53
- …
- 85
- Next Page »